Lalive, Landais and Zweim¨
uller,2012] and countercyclical [Cr´
epon et al.,2012;Kroft and Notowidigdo,
2011]. Hence, the optimal replacement rate is above that given by the Baily formula and countercyclical.
From a theoretical perspective the empirical finding that m/M>1is surprising because it is not
consistent with the behavior of the search-and-matching model with Nash bargaining, commonly used by
macroeconomists to analyse optimal UI over the business cycle [for example, Mitman and Rabinovich,
2011]. Indeed, we show at the beginning of Section 2that m/M<1in that model. The reason why
m< Mis simple. Consider a reduction in UI. There is a microeffect: the reduction in unemployment
from higher job-search effort, measured by m. In addition, the Nash-bargained wage falls because the
outside option of workers falls. This reduction in wage leads firms to hire even more, thus reinforcing
the microeffect. Hence the macroeffect, measured by M, is stronger than the microeffect.
To rationalize the empirical findings that m/Mis above one and countercyclical, Section 2develops
a parsimonious macroeconomic model of UI. Our model builds on the framework of Michaillat [2012a].
That framework modifies the search-and-matching model with Nash bargaining by assuming that (i) the
wage schedule is rigid instead of arising from Nash bargaining; and (ii) the production function has
diminishing marginal returns to labor instead of constant returns to labor. Michaillat [2012a] shows
that realistic unemployment fluctuations arise with assumption (i) and jobs are rationed in recessions
with assumptions (i) and (ii)—that is, the labor market does not converge to full employment even when
search efforts are arbitrarily large. We show that in this model, m/Mis above one and countercyclical
under assumptions (i) and (ii).
First, we prove that m/M>1. Intuitively, the number of jobs available is limited because of
diminishing marginal returns to labor. Hence, searching more to increase one’s probability of finding a
job mechanically decreases others’ probability of finding one of the few jobs available. Since m/M>1,
our formula calls for a higher replacement rate than the Baily formula. The higher replacement rate
discourages job search and thus corrects the negative rat-race externality imposed by jobseekers on
others. This externality arises because jobseekers search taking the job-finding rate as given, without
internalizing their negative influence on the job-finding rate of others. Since the replacement rate given
by the Baily formula is also the replacement rate offered by small private insurers, our formula suggests
that small private insurers would not provide enough insurance against unemployment.
Second, we prove that m/Mis countercyclical, and also that the macroelasticity Mis procyclical.
Intuitively, recessions are periods of acute job shortage during which job search and matching frictions
have little influence on the labor market equilibrium. Therefore, aggregate search efforts have little
influence on unemployment and the macroelasticity Mis small. Since the microelasticity mremains
broadly the same, the wedge m/Mis large in recessions.
2