2 - Theoretical background: factors influencing the labor market impact of
the crisis
During and after the Great Recession, labor markets have experienced divergent trends which are
only partly due to differences in growth rates. In fact, the ability of different labor markets to limit
job losses during the crisis reflects a combination of factors.
First, the structure of the economy, understood as the relative importance of the sectors that were
most vulnerable during the crisis, is relevant. For example, the construction sector, which is one of
the major employer in Spain, has been hard hit by the bursting of the real estate bubble. Or the
United Kingdom, recognized as the financial center of Europe, has suffered most from the
consequences of the financial crisis.
In addition, the availability of public resources for fiscal stimulus packages has played an important
role in alleviating the negative effects of the crisis. Some countries, such as China or Thailand, have
allocated the equivalent of 10% of their GDP to this type of measures while other countries, in
particular the eurozone's periphery, have been penalized by restrictions on their public debt.
Finally, a key role is played by the capacity of the labor market institutions – intended as the
combination of Employment Protection Legislation (EPL), wage setting mechanisms, unemployment
benefits and active labor market policies (ALMPs) which characterize the labor market of each
country – to absorb and accommodate shock.
Blanchard et al. (2014) argue that countries should design their labor market institutions to
maximize both micro flexibility and macro flexibility while protecting workers and preserve existing
business relations. This is not a simple task, and implies delicate tradeoffs.
Macro flexibility is defined as the capacity of an economy to keep low and stable unemployment
rates in presence of a macroeconomic shock. In this case, wage setting mechanisms play an
important role, especially the collective bargaining structure. During the crises, some of the
countries which managed to limit employment losses – as Germany, Thailand and South Korea –
displayed adjustments in real wages, or at least a slowdown of their growth. In general, country
which display more wage flexibility tend to present lower collective bargaining coverage and no
minimum wages, while a strongly centralized collective bargaining structure favors wage rigidity.
On the other hand, micro flexibility is the ability of the job market to reallocate workers in a way
that sustains growth. This must be achieved while minimizing the welfare loss of workers.
In this framework, Atkinson (1984) distinguishes two different kinds of flexibility.
First, the possibility of firms to adapt the number of workers to the economic situation, also known
as external flexibility. This capacity mainly depends on the degree of employment protection on
short and long term contracts, which regulates individual and collective dismissals. While the degree
of EPL varies widely across countries, the general tendency since the 1990s has been to reduce the
strictness of employment protection.
Second, an efficient reallocation of workers could be achieved without variations in the number of
employees, which is known as internal flexibility. This happens by adjusting the working time or by
reorganizing workers along the production process, which requires a labor force with broad and
high skills. The use of policies which enhance internal flexibility has been widespread during the
crises, in order to limit dismissals. Since 2008, the majority of countries have experienced important
reductions in the working hours and the share of part time jobs has increased significantly.