3
I. INTRODUCTION
Just as national regulation was broadened in the 19th and 20th centuries to protect workers and
consumers (e.g., anti-trust legislation, health standards, corporate governance, bank
supervision) from the excesses of free markets, there is now a general recognition that
globalization needs a regulatory framework in the 21st century that is less fragmented than
what exists today, and international financial institutions—in particular, the International
Monetary Fund (IMF)—can be expected to have major roles in this area. In fact, the IMF has
already taken steps in this direction (e.g., evaluating countries’ compliance with international
data standards, moving in the direction of setting a new surveillance remit, and launching a
multilateral consultation on addressing global imbalances). However, for the IMF to play an
important role in global governance, it is essential to enhance its credibility as an
international cooperative institution: there is widespread recognition that the quotas (IMF
capital shares), voting rights, and voice imbalances have become progressively worse.1 The
effectiveness of the IMF has been questioned both inside and outside the institution not only
because members’ quotas have become increasingly out of line with countries’ economic
weight (measured by GDP) in the global economy, but also because there is a growing
recognition that some important aspects of members’ economic weight and other variables
that should have a bearing on voting rights are not captured in the current quota formulas.
These concerns are reflected in the International Monetary and Financial Committee
communiqué of April 22, 2006, which stated that the IMF’s effectiveness and credibility as a
cooperative institution must be safeguarded and its governance further enhanced, and
emphasized the importance of fair voice and representation for all members. The IMF has
adopted a two-stage process for quota and voice reform, with initial ad hoc increases for the
clearly most underrepresented members in the first stage, and more fundamental reforms in
the second stage.2 While the specific reform proposals for the second stage are just beginning
to be discussed, there is already considerable concern among developing countries that the
discussion is being confined to an unduly narrow area, and important issues are not being
raised. These concerns are only magnified by the concerted efforts being made in many
quarters to validate the traditional approach of basing voting power in the IMF largely on
countries’ respective weight in the world economy, with the justification being provided in
terms of the mandate of the institution. However, representatives from developing countries
have rightly pointed out that the IMF mandate is not as narrow as some would have us
1 Quotas are currently calculated according to a member's gross domestic product, current account transactions,
and official reserves. The quota largely determines a member's voting power in IMF decisions and is reviewed
every five years, with the next review due in 2008 (see Section II).
2 A two-stage process with an ad hoc increase in the first stage is not consistent with the need for a
comprehensive review, and the Finance Minister of India was correct in saying during the IMF-World Bank
Annual Meetings in Singapore in October 2006 that “[b]y definition, a comprehensive reallocation of quotas to
reinforce legitimacy cannot be achieved by a short-term ad hoc approach." Equally valid is the point that the
under-representation of developing countries undermines the credibility and legitimacy of the Bretton Woods
Institutions, which hinders effectiveness and relevance of these institutions, as noted in the G-24 communiqué
during those meetings.